Microeconomics

The Price Elasticity of Demand

Updated Jun 26, 2020

In economics, the law of supply and demand, the quantity demanded of a good or service increases if its price falls. To see how strong this effect is, we can use the concept of elasticity. More specifically, the price elasticity of demand (PED). Depending on what we are analyzing, different demand elasticities can be considered (e.g., price elasticity, cross-prize elasticity, income elasticity). The most relevant of them is the price elasticity of demand, which describes to what extent the quantity demanded of a good is affected by a change in its price. Many factors affect the elasticity, so we will start by looking at its most relevant determinants.

Determinants

The PED is determined by a multitude of economic, social, and psychological factors that each influence consumer preferences and choices in a unique way. The most important ones are the necessity of the product, the availability of close substitutes, the proportion of income devoted to the product, and the relevant time horizon.

1) Necessity of the Product

If a good is considered a necessity (e.g., water, bread, toilet paper, etc.), a large change in the price of the good won’t affect its demand significantly. In that case, we speak of inelastic demand. The reason for this is that people always have to satisfy their basic needs, so they do not respond much to price changes for basic goods. If a product is considered a luxury good, however, demand will be much more elastic because people do not need those products to survive.

2) Availability of Close Substitutes

Close substitutes allow consumers to switch between different goods that satisfy the same (or similar) needs. Thus if a good has one or more close substitutes, demand will be rather elastic. In that case, people can buy the substitute to satisfy the same needs if the price of a product increases. On the other hand, if there are no close substitutes available, consumers cannot just switch between similar products so they won’t respond strongly to a price change.

3) Proportion of Income Devoted to Product

Products that are expensive (i.e., take up a high proportion of the available income) tend to have more elastic demand. In absolute terms, a 1 percent increase in the price of an expensive good is more significant than a 1 percent change in the price of a cheap good. As a result, consumers generally respond more strongly to price changes if they have to devote a larger proportion of their income to a certain product.

4) Relevant Time Horizon

In most cases, demand is more elastic in the long run as it is in the short run. There are many occasions where consumers face high switching costs in the short-run (because of binding contracts, opportunity costs, etc.). Those costs are usually lower in the long run because contracts can be allowed to expire, and there is more time to prepare and to evaluate all available options.

Types of Elasticity

There are different types of elasticity. In particular, a demand curve can be elastic, unit elastic, or inelastic. Since elasticity is always measured at a certain point, a single curve can have segments of all three types simultaneously. To see how this is possible, we will have to crunch the numbers and look at how elasticity is computed. The PED is defined as the percentage change in quantity demanded divided by the percentage change in the price of a good. This can be illustrated using the following formula.

Price elasticity of demand

To give an example, let’s assume that an increase of 2% in the price of ice cream causes consumers to buy 6% less of it. According to our formula, the elasticity, in this case, can be computed as 6% / 2% = 3. So the price elasticity of demand equals 3. Please note that in some cases, we need a new formula (i.e., the midpoint formula) to calculate the price elasticity of demand. More specifically, the midpoint formula is required when we try to calculate elasticities between two points on a demand curve.

In addition to that, we also need some classification to work with the number we calculated above. Right now, it does not say much. This is where the different types of elasticity mentioned above come into play. With their help, we can classify the curve and thus interpret the result.

  • If the elasticity is greater than one, a demand curve is said to be elastic. In this case, consumers respond strongly to price changes. As a result, the quantity demanded changes proportionally more than the price.
  • If the elasticity is equal to one, a demand curve is said to be unit elastic. In that case, consumers respond proportionally to price changes, which means the quantity demanded will also change in the same proportion as the price.
  • If the elasticity is less than one, a demand curve is said to be inelastic. In this case, consumers do not respond strongly to price changes. Therefore the quantity demanded changes proportionally less than the price.
Hence, since elasticity in our example is equal to 3, we can conclude that the demand for ice cream is elastic at this point. Once again, it is important to note that this elasticity may change as we move along the demand curve, so there may be other examples where the ice cream has different elasticities on the same curve. This is because we use relative proportions to calculate the elasticities.

Additional Demand Elasticities

1) Cross-Price elasticity of demand

The cross-price elasticity of demand is used to measure by how much the quantity demanded of a good changes as the price of another good increases. Thus, it is defined as the percentage change in quantity demanded of good 1 divided by the percentage change in the price of good 2. This results in the following formula.

Cross-Price Elasticity of Demand

If the cross-price elasticity is a negative number, the two goods are said to be complements. In this case, an increase in the price of good 1 reduces the demand for good 2. On the other hand, if the elasticity is positive, the goods are said to be substitutes, since an increase in the price of good 1 results in an increase in the quantity demanded of good 2.

2) Income Elasticity of Demand

The income elasticity of demand is used to measure to what extent the quantity demanded of a good changes as consumer income changes. It can be computed as the percentage change in quantity demanded divided by the percentage change in consumer income. Again, this can be illustrated using a simple formula.

Income Elasticity of Demand

If the income elasticity of a good is a positive number, it is considered a normal good, because a higher income increases the quantity demanded. By contrast, if the good has a negative income elasticity, it is regarded as an inferior good. In the case of those goods, a higher income will result in a lower quantity demanded.

Summary

The price elasticity of demand measures how the quantity demanded of a good or service changes as its price changes. It is determined by several factors, including the necessity of the product, the availability of close substitutes, the proportion of income devoted to the product, and the relevant time horizon. The demand curve of a good or service can be elastic (i.e., greater than 1), unit elastic (i.e., equal to 1), or inelastic (i.e., less than 1). It is possible to have different types of elasticities along the same demand curve. Apart from the price elasticity of demand, there are two additional demand elasticities: the cross-price elasticity of demand, and the income elasticity of demand.